Monday, 22 August 2011

Sale of Goods vs Sale of Debt


SALE OF GOODS
AND SALE OF
DEBT:                      
A COMPARATIVE
ANALYSIS
MUGHEES SHAUKAT
ISLAMIC LAW OF CONTRACT S
2010
PAPER
INCEIF
12/6/2010
2

TABLE OF CONTENTS

No.   Topic                    Page No.
1.  Introduction………………………………………………………………….        03
2.  Al-Bay In Islam; The Foundational Robes………………………………      04
2.1 Pivotal Understanding of Mal and Mal Mutaqawwam.…………….        05
3. The Tale of the Two T’s
     3.1. Tangible property right vs intangible property right …………….            07
4. Calling The Right Rights Has Always Been The Order Of The Day
     4.1 corporeal property right vs property right in the obligation
           of the debtor:……………………………………………………………..      08
5. The Writing Has Always Been On The Wall
     5.1. Bai al-dayn as sale of debt………………………………………………    12
6. Wisdom Personified
     6.1. It was always meant to be like this………………………………………   18
     6.1.1. Case of derivatives……………………………………………………….. 20
     6.1.2. Case of futures (which potentially can spill the future)…………………….   21
     6.1.3 Case of Sale and Securitization of Debt………………………………..  23
7. Conclusion……………………………………………………………………......   29
Appendix
Bibliography


3

                                                        ABSTARCT


Law is concerned, primarily, with fairness whereas social good, including economic good, is conceived in
terms  of  provisions  that  depend,  ultimately,  on  production.  Fairness  is  necessary  for  ensuring  dignity
whereas  wealth  is  needed  to  guaranty  security.  It  goes  without  saying  that  Islamic  economics  as  a
discipline  cares  about  efficiency  as well  as  justice  and  fairness.  It  is well  aware  of  the  fact  that  in  a
balanced  realization  the  two  reinforce  each other. This paper will propose  to demonstrate  the  ever  so
prevalent  and  dynamically  wisdomful  nature  of  Islam  even  enshrined  through  Islamic  finance  by
venturing  into  a  detailed  debate  rooted  from  and  to  the  very  foundational  paradigm  of  TRADE,  the
concept of exchange of property, selling and buying. Incept- ionizing  from the submerged argumentation
over  the permissible stacked up with  the non-permissible stretching  to  the dimensions of understanding
the basic concepts and then gliding to the depths of despair by permitting the non-permissible pinnacled
by modern financial instruments and concluding in more a self explanatory parlance.










4

1.0.  INTRODUCTION:
Most of the contracts entered into in Islamic banking and finance are in the category of
exchange contracts (al-muawadat), which are essentially trading-based. This is quite to
the  contrary with  the activities  in  conventional  banking  and  finance, which  are mainly
lending-based activities. When  the contracts are exchange contracts,  they necessarily
entail  the  exchange  of  goods,  services,  or  usufruct,  for  a  consideration  or  price.  The
most common forms of the contracts of exchange are either buying and selling (ai-bay')
which  involves  the  sale  of  goods,  or  leasing  (al-ijarah) which  involves  the  sale  of  the
usufruct (manfa'ah).  In both,  the subject matter (Mahall al-  'aqd)  is  the central focus of
the  legal  effects  accruing  from  the  valid  conclusion  of  the  contracts.  In  Islamic
jurisprudence, exchange contracts require more stringent fulfillment of the conditions of
the  subject matter  (shurut mahall  al-  'aqd),  particularly  on  the  conditions  of  certainty,
ascertainability and proprietary value. This  is because, exchange contracts  involve  the
exchange  of  counter  values,  as  opposed  to  the  uni-lateral  contracts  of  gratuity  (altabarru'at),
 which give one-sided benefit to the recipient. 
In  an  Islamic  contract  of  exchange,  the  counter  values  -  goods/usufruct  and
price/consideration - are the subject matters of the contract. To be valid subject matters
of  a  contract,  these  counter  values  need  to  be  properties  (amwal) which  are  certain,
valued and beneficial (mutaqawwam). This is to ensure that their exchange would give
a fair and legal commercial benefit for both sides of the contracting parties. The fairness
of the transaction can be ensured by the ability of both parties to appreciate and benefit
from  the proprietary worth of both  counter  values  in  the  subject matter and give  their
consent to the exchange accordingly.
5

Of late, the range of possible counter values and subject matters has expanded so as to
include certain rights, which proprietary value and capacity to be valid subject matters of
contracts  may  still  be  very  much  debatable.  These  possible  counter  values  include
mostly abstract rights such as, the rights to receivables, the rights to future benefits from
a concluded contract, and the rights to license and concession.
The main  issue  is,  can  these  rights be  traded or  sold  for a  consideration? Can  these
rights be valid subject matters  for an  Islamic project-financing contract, which consists
mainly of a series of exchange contracts? For example, if a person or company obtains
a  license  to  develop  a  piece  of  landed  property  into  an  industrial  area  consisting  of
factories and other paraphernalia, can  the person or company sell  the  right  to others?
Alternatively, can the person or company securitize the right in order to get the financing
for the project?
Thus,  it becomes ever so pivotal  for one  to know what qualifies  to be exchanged and
the opposite and even more so when one wants to analyze and that to in a comparative
tone. this article will therefore make an effort by starting from the very scratch seeking to
first scrutinize and hence establish an understanding of what Islam means when it talks
about property and property right with special reference to these rights and their validity
to be proper subject matters in Islamic contracts of exchange. 
In  doing  so,  the  article  analyses  the  classical  and  contemporary  fiqh  writings  on  the
issue. Then, the study examines the application and relevance of the fiqh interpretations
and develop from the parlance  in a self explanatory approach the comparison between
which  exchange  is  permitted  and which  is not  by  focusing  on  sale  of  dayn  to  sale of
6

other  forms, evidenced and supported by  to some of  the concepts  in modern banking
and finance contracts as will be unfolded by the discussion.
2.0                AL-BAY IN ISLAM; THE FOUNDATIONAL ROBES 
                                                THE STARTING POINT
2.1.     PIVOTAL UNDERSTANDING OF MAL AND MAL MUTAQAWWAM:
As a general rule, the subject matter in a contract of exchange should be property (mal)
that  is  of  value  (mutaqawwam)  and  is  capable  of  ownership  (milkiyyah).  Thus,  it  is
important for us to analyze the concept of mal and mal mutaqawwam. 
In the dictionary, definition of mal (its plural - amwal) is simple and straight forward, i.e.,
"whatever you own from all matters". However, the legal defmitions given by the jurists
to mal are various. This is mainly due to their differences in describing the focus of the
proprietary  aspects  of  things  (manat  maliyyah  al-ashya').  Some  of  them  say  that
properties are limited to corporeal matters only (a 'yan), whilst others say that they also
include  usufructs  (manafi')  and  rights  (huquq). Majority  of  the  classical  Hanafi  jurists
were  in  favour  of  the  first  approach  towards  defining mal,  i.e.,  limiting  it  to  corporeal
matters only. For example, Ibn Abidin defined mal as "that which human nature inclines,
and can be stored for future needs.
In  other  occasions,  he  described mal  as  "corporeal matter  (  'ayan)  that  is  capable  of
being  controlled and acquired", and  "  ...  is  limited  to  corporeal matters  (a'yan),  to  the
exclusion of usufructs  (manafi'}".He  further said,  "the proprietary aspect of mal  is also
established  by  its worth  or  value  (taqawwum)  that  allows  the  lawful  enjoyment  of  the
property.  Interestingly,  Ibn  'Abidin  recognized  that  usufructs  can  be  subjects  of
7

ownership  (milk),  yet,  they  are  not  amwal  because  they  cannot  be  made  specific
subjects to dealings and transactions (tasarruf).
Relating the concept of mal to the subject matter in a contract of exchange, article 363
of  the Majallah provides  that  "a  thing, which admits  the  consequences of a  sale,  is a
thing sold, which exists,  is capable of delivery, and  is mal mutaqawwim". The Majallah
also  adopts  the  l:Ianafis'  view  in  limiting  the  subject  matter  in  a  sale  contract  to
corporeal matters (a 'yan) only. For example, article 150 provides that the subject matter
of sale (mahall al-bay') is what is known as al-mabi'. Al-mabi' is defined in article 151 as"
a  thing  fixed  and  individually  perceptible('ayn)  designated  at  the  sale,  and  is  the
principal object of  the sale, because  the benefit  is derived  from  the  things  ('ayn) alone
and the price is the means for the mutual exchange of property." 'Ayn on the other hand
is defined in article 159 as "a thing which is fixed and individually perceptible", giving the
examples of a horse, a chair, a heap of com which exists and is present and a sum of
money.
The  jumhur  comprising  of  the  Maliki,  Shafi'i  and  Hanbali  schools  took  the  second
approach  to  the  definition  of  mal,  whereby  they  considered  rights  and  usufructs  as
property as  long as  they are  related  to property and any assets of value: According  to
the  jumhur's view,  in order  to be mal mutaqawwam,  two essential elements should be
present. First,  the usufruct of  the  thing should be  legally permissible; and second,  it  is
customarily  treated  as  property  or  of  proprietary  value.  Almost  all  contemporary
scholars  prefer  the  view  of  the  jumhur  in  the  inclusion  of  rights  and  usufructs  in  the
meaning of mal.
                                         
8

3.0.                            THE TALE OF THE TWO T’s
3.1.           TANGIBLE PROPERTY RIGHT VS INTANGIBLE PROPERTY RIGHT:
An  issue  that may  arise  in  relation  to  a  corporeal  property  right(Haqq  mali  'ayni    is
whether its object should always be a material and tangible thing ('ayn maddi), or,  could
it also be an abstract and intangible thing ('ayn ma'nawi) as well? 
According  to  al-  'Ibadi,  an  abstract  right  can  still  be  considered  as  a  kind  of  property
right,  because  it  is  capable  of  being  valued  by  property  and  is  giving  its  owner  a
proprietary value (qimah maliyyyah) capable of being valued by pecuniary or monetary
measures.  'Ali al-Khaifif also considered an abstract and  intangible property  right as a
special form of ownership right, i.e., Haqq mali 'ayni. AI-Durayni further argues that the
object  of  ownership  (mahall  al-milkiyyah) may  also  include  abstract  rights,  and  is  not
necessarily limited to material and tangible things only?
Thus,  it  can  be  concluded  that  corporeal  property  right  also  includes  abstract  and
intangible rights. In fact, in the decision by the OIC Fiqh Academy, intellectual property
rights have been said to be property rights that are capable of being bought and sold for
a consideration, despite of their intangible nature.
The discussion on  intangible  rights opens  the door  to other analogous  situations. For
example, whether other abstract and intangible rights, such as the rights to license and
concession enjoy  the same position with  intellectual property rights. An analysis of  the
decision  according  intellectual  property  right  the  status  of  Haqq  mali  'ayni,  that  is
capable of being a subject matter of exchange contracts, indicates a number of factors
that qualify intellectual property right to its current status. The factors for its qualification
as Haqq mali 'ayni can be summarized as:
9

•  Its nature as a property with special characteristics;
•  It has proprietary value according to custom;
•  It can be owned exclusively by its owner, i.e., the owner is free to benefit from the
property and prevent others from trespassing or interfering with the property.
•  The property is deliverable and exsists
•  It is not prohibited to own by Shariah

4.0. CALLING  THE RIGHT RIGHTS HAS ALWAYS BEEN  THE         
ORDER OF THE DAY

4.1. CORPOREAL PROPERTY RIGHT VS PROPERTY RIGHT IN THE OBLIGATION
OF THE DEBTOR:
A more controversial issue pertaining is whether certain abstract property rights should
be  regarded  as  dependent  on  the  corporeal matter  (  'ayn),  i.e.,  a  kind  of  choses  in
possession;  or  should  it  be  regarded  as  a  kind  of  proprietary  right  established  in  the
liability (al-Haqq al-thabit fi al-dhimmah), i.e., a kind of choses in action?
If the abstract proprietary right is dependent upon the corporeal matter, it is arguably an
independent asset  ('ayn)  and  thus,  the  rule  pertaining  to  the  avoidance  of  riba  in  the
exchange of debts and monies,  i.e.,  that both counter values must be equivalent and
the  delivery  be  prompt, may  not  apply. On  the  other  hand,  if  the  abstract  proprietary
right  is  regarded as established  in  the  liability  (fi al-dhimmah),  it  is arguably a  form of
debt  (dayn), hence,  the  rule of equivalence and promptness  in  the exchange of debts
10

and monies may apply. Similarly,  if  the  right  is considered as a debt,  the  rule against
bay'  al-kali'  bi  al-kali'  should  also  be  observed.  It  is  thought  that an  abstract  property
right may still be attached  to a corporeal matter, such as  that of  intellectual properties
and products. Yet, some other abstract proprietary rights may not be clearly attached to
a corporeal matter, and are arguably more in the nature of rights fi al-dhimmah, such as
the  rights  to  future  receivables  in  a  contract  of  sale  with  deferred  payment  (bay'
bithaman ajil). The issue becomes pertinent in considering the legality of the sale of the
right  to  receivables  from sales contracts at a discounting, as  it has been practiced,  for
example in Malaysia, for the creation of some of its Islamic bonds.
Being  a  debt  or  analogous  to  a  debt,  implies  the  treatment  of  this  property  right  as
similar to that of the treatment of money, the exchange of which, is subject to the rules
pertaining  to  avoidance  of  riba  al-fadl  and  riba  al-nasi'ah  in  the  exchange  of  ribawi
items.  According  to  the  rule,  the  right  in  debt  cannot  in  general  be  exchanged  for
another debt, deferred  (bay' al-kali' bi al-kali' or alternatively  termed as bay' al-dayn bi
al-dayn). Thus,  in a contract, say  to sell a right  to receivables  from sales,  the rules  for
the sale of debts with money will apply - i.e. the exchange has to be cash! spot, and if
made  in  the  same  currency  -  the  exchange  should  be  at  par.  If  the  transaction  is
deferred, this may amount to bay' al-kali bi al-kali' which will also be tantamount to riba
al-nasi'ah. The amount  should also be  the  same  if  the purchase price  is  in  the  same
currency with  the original debts  in order  to avoid  the occurrence  riba al-fadl. The view
that the right to receivables in sale contract is dayn makes the securitization of the right
to receivables almost impossible. 
11

The  prevalence  of  this  view  also  explains  the  objections  that  some  of  the Malaysian
Islamic bonds receive from the other quarters of the Muslim world. Another example of
an  analogous  situation  where  haqq mali  fi  al-dhimmah  in  sale  contract  becomes  an
issue  is what  the Hanbali”s describe as bay' al-mawsuf  fi aldhimmah  ,i.e., purchase of
an 'abstractly defined good' in the obligation of the seller.
For example, the Hanbalis treat manufacture sale (bay' al-istisna') as a form of bay' almawsuf
  fi  al-dhimmah,  with  a  necessary  condition  that  the  buyer must  pay  in  full  at
once,  and  is  bound  by  the  contract  as  long  as  the  final  product  agrees  with  the
contractual description. The condition of spot full payment is essentially to avoid the rule
against  bay'  al-kali'  bi  al-kali'. However,  due  to  the  practical  difficulty  in  imposing  full
payment at  the  time of a manufacture contract,  the Hanbalis would alternatively allow
for  partial  payments  or  even  fully  deferred  payment  using  an  alternative  legal
description of the contract. In this case, the contract is not treated as bay' al-mawsuf fi
al-dhimmah, but rather, a contract of sale of the raw materials ('ayn), actually delivered,
with a condition  (shart)  that  they be constructed  into a building,  the payment of which
may  be  deferred  and  made  subject  to  the  final  product  satisfying  the  contractual
description.The latter contract, thus, amounts to a sale of 'ayn for dayn which is allowed,
instead of a sale of dayn for dayn which is not allowed.
The  second  line  of  opinion  on  the  issue  of  whether  the  right  to  receivables  in  sales
contract should be treated as Haq mali ayni or Haq mali fi-al-dhimmah is that, the right
is considered as an independent property right(Haq mail). The argument given is, since
the right to receivable in sale contract is attached to real corporeal asset ('ayn), i.e., the
goods that form the subject matter of the sale contract, it is not a debt (dayn). The right
12

to receivables seen in this light is therefore an independent form of haq mali and can be
traded like any other property rights?
 An  analysis  of  the  view  suggests  that  the  exchange  of  these  types  of  rights  is
considered  as  the  exchange  of  'ayn  for  'ayn  or  'ayn  for  dayn,  and  thus,  is  not
objectionable. In a similar line, the Hanafis have allowed bay' al-istisna:, defining it as a
sale of an 'ayn though one that does not exist yet. Here, the Hanafis treat the property
which is yet to be constructed as an 'ayn, not dayn nor fi al-dhimmah. Hence, a building
to  be  constructed  or  partially  under  construction  is  already  treated  as  an  'ayn  –  a
corporeal matter - though in reality it may only be an expectation of a corporeal property
to exist in the future. This expectation may be described as a right to a future corporeal
property, thus, a corporeal proprietary right (Haq mali 'ayni). Since this proprietary right
is obviously attached  to a corporeal property (  'ayn) -  though one  that  is to exist  in  the
future - it is corporeal in nature ( 'ayni). The combination of these characteristics justifies
the entity  to be  that of ~aq mali  'ayni which  is different  from Haqq mali  fi al-dhimmah
because  the  former  is  categorically  a  corporeal matter  ('ayn)  and  can  be  exchanged
deferred (dayn) without triggering the rule against the sale of debt for debt.
From the preceding arguments, it seems that the division between the concepts of 'ayn
and dayn have not been decisively drawn. Certain situations that may look like a liability
(fi dhimmah) can still be argued  to be an asset  ('ayn).hence  it becomes  imperative  for
us  to venture on  further even more deeply  to understand what sale of debt  it and  the
rules related to  it and to decide on  its permissibility or not and  if so what effects  it can
have in the eternity of it.

13


 
5.0.               THE WRITING HAS ALWAYS BEEN ON THE WALL

5.1. BAI AL-DAYN AS SALE OF DEBT:
"Dayn" means "debt" and "Bai' " means sale. "Bai'-al-dayn", therefore, connotes the sale
of debt. According  to Majalah al-ahkam al-adliyah, no 158  ; Dayn defines as  the  thing
due i.e the amount of money owed by a certain debtor. Al-Dayn can be either monetary,
or a commodity,  i.e  food or metal. Bay' Al-Dayn or debt  trading or sale of debt can be
defined as the sale of payable right or receivable debt either to the debtor himself, or to
any  third  party.  This  type  of  sale  is  usually  for  immediate  payment  or  for  deferred
payment. 
The Shariah permits the selling of debt by its equivalent in quantity and time of maturity
by way of hawalah. This  form of debt  trading  is accepted by all schools of  Islamic  law
provided it is paid in full and thus gives no benefit to the purchaser. The rationale for this
ruling is that financial transactions involving debt should never allow deferred payment,
as  this would be  regarded as Riba or Bay’ al-Kali bi al-Kali which  is prohibited by  the
Prohpet S.A.W.  (International Journal Of  Islamic Financial Services, vol 1, no 2, Saiful
Azhar)
According to most Hanafis, Hanbalis and Shafie jurists, it is not allowed to sell Al-Dayn
to non debtor or a third party at all. However Malikis, and some Hanafis and Shafie jurist
allowed selling of debt to third party with some conditions which are :- 
14

a-  The ability of seller to deliver the debts; 
b-  The debt must be mustaqir or confirmed and the contract must be performed on the
spot; 
c-   The  debt  cannot  be  created  from  the  sale  of  currency  (gold  and  silver)  to  be
delivered in the future and the payment is not of the same type as debt, and if it is so,
the rate should be the same to avoid Riba. 
d-  The debt should be goods that are saleable, even before they are received. This is
to ensure  that  the debt  is not of  the  food  type which cannot be  traded  to  the debtor.  (
Hasyiah Ad-Dusuqi, vol 3, p 63 ) 
The  main  issue  here  is,  whether  it  is  permissible  to  sell  a  confirmed  debt  which  is
backed by a non ribawi goods at discounted price? 
Mainstream  Islamic  scholars  have  put  a  plug  on  the  possibility  of  earning  profit  by
confirming  that  any  sale  of  debt  (Bay’-al-dayn)  or  transfer  of  debt  (Hawalat-al-dayn)
must  be  at  face  value.  This means  in  the  above  question,  when  the  bank  buys  the
instrument  of  debt  (shahada-al-dayn)  from  the  original  buyer,  it  is  not  entitled  to  any
discount. Doors of  riba are closed shut by disallowing any difference between what  it
pays  (purchase  price of  the  instrument)  and what  it  receives  on maturity  (its maturity
value). Notwithstanding  the clear verdict against such  transaction, some  Islamic banks
have been offering Islamic bill discounting products. They essentially treat debt as any
other physical asset that can be traded at a negotiated price. 
15

In  fact,  the  prohibition  of  Bay’-al-dayn  is  a  logical  consequence  of  the  prohibition  of
"riba"  or  interest.  A  "debt"  receivable  in monetary  terms  corresponds  to money,  and
every  transaction where money  is exchanged  from  the same denomination of money,
the price must be at par value. Any increase or decrease from one side is tantamount to
"riba" and can never be allowed in Shariah. 
Some scholars argue some forms of Bay’ ad-Dayn is permissible, and they said that the
permissibility of Bay ad-Dayn is: - 
restricted  to a  case where  the debt  is  created  through a  sale of a  commodity.  In  this
case, they say, the debt represents the sold commodity and its sale may be taken as a
sale of the commodity. They said that on the conditions set by Maliki mazhab “payment
is not of  the same  type as dayn, and  if  it  is so,  the  rate should be  the same  to avoid
Riba”.  In  this  context  of  the  sale  of  securitized  debt,  the  characteristics  of  securities
differentiate  it  from  currency,  and  hence,  it  is  not  bound  by  the  conditions  for
exchanging  of Ribawi  goods,  therefore,  selling  debt which  is  represented  non-Ribawi
asset is permissible to be discounted. (Securities Commission Shariah Advisory Council
Resolution(p19) 
The debt is created by the sale of goods and services through the sale-based modes of
Islamic Finance, particularly Murabahah. The debt  is created by  the Murabahah mode
of financing permitted by  the Shariah and  the price, according  to  the Shariah Scholars
themselves, includes the profit on the transaction and not interest. Therefore, when the
bank sells such debt instrument at a discount, what it is relinquishing, or what the buyer
is getting, is not interest but rather a share in the profit. 
16

The  arguments,  however,  have  been  rejected  by majority  of  the  jurists. According  to
them, once the commodity is sold, its ownership is passed on to the purchaser and it is
no  longer commodity of  the seller. What  the seller owns  is nothing other  than money,
therefore if he sells the debt, it is regarded as the sale of money and it cannot be termed
by any stretch of imagination as the sale of the commodity. This is why the view has not
been accepted by the overwhelming majority of the contemporary scholars.  (Mufti Taqi
Uthmani, An Introduction to Islamic Finance) 
It is considered as the sale of rights on a debt and not the debt itself. In that sense, it is
allowed to sell it to the third party and also either with discount or not. However, majority
of Shariah scholar  rejected  this view as  the  right of  the debt  is still considered as  the
debt  itself. Such  sale would  be  nothing  but  a  disguised way  of  receiving  and  paying
interest. 
This  is  the same as  the principles of debt settlement. They say  that  there  is a Hadith
narrated  by  al-Bukhari  that  strongly  support  debt  reduction, while  parties  opposing  to
the  concept  are  unable  to  provide  any  strong  arguments  except  to  justify  that  debt
reduction  contains element of Riba al-nasiah and Riba al-Fadl. Such argument  is not
correct because the process of settling a debt does not constitute a trade. Furthermore,
those opposed to debt reduction or discounting have overlooked the mechanism of Ibra’
which  involves  the  discharge  of  the  whole  or  part  of  one’s  claim  on  a  debtor.  Ibra
(rebate)  which  is  similar  to  debt  reduction  is  accepted  by  Shariah  jurist. 
 However,  the  opposing  scholars  do  not  agree with  the  analogy  and  considered  ibra’
and  sale  of  debt  with  a  discounted  price  is  different  in  its  objective  and  its
17

implementation.  The  prohibition  is  also  based  on  the  concept  of  Sadd  az-Zariah  or
closing the potential Riba from occuring. 
Some parties in Malaysia encourage the development for debt discounting as an Islamic
Financial product on the basis that it represents an important field of short term and self
liquidating  investment,  because  the  terms  of  negotiable  instruments  do  not  in  most
cases  extend  beyond  six  months  especially  in  trade  based  debt  discounting  (Saiful
Azhar , International Journal Of Islamic Financial Services, vol 1, no 2) 
The  Islamic  Fiqh Academy  of  Jeddah which  is  the  largest  representative  body  of  the
Shariah scholars and is represented by all the Muslim countries, in its 16th convention
at Mekka on 5-10th  January 2002 has  re-discussed  the  issue and  stated  that  sale of
debt is prohibited including the following:- 
a)  Sale of debts  to debtors with a deferred payment plan exceeding debt amount as
this can be considered as Riba al-Fadl and Riba an-Nasiah. (Jadwalah ad-Dayn) 
b)  Sale of debts to a third party with a deferred payment plan whether the debt is paid
with the same type of kind or not; as this can be considered as sale of debt with debt 
(bai’ al-kali bi al-Kali which is clearly prohibited by Prophet Muhammad) 
According to the academy, commercial papers such as cheques, promissory notes and
bill  of  exchange  cannot  be  sold  at  a  discount  as  there  is  element  of  Riba. 
It  is not allowed  to deal,  issue, distribute or  trade with Riba based Bonds because  the
element of Riba  is present.  It  is not allowed  to deal with debt notes  in  the secondary
18

market  as  it  involves  discounts  and  sale  of  debts  to  third  parties  which  has  Riba
elements. 
The Islamic Fiqh academy proposed that a Shariah approved alternative for discounted
papers  and  and  sale  and  purchase  of  bonds  is  sale  in  the  form  of  goods;  with  a
condition  that  the seller hands over  the good during aqad (contract),  it  is allowed even
though the price of the good is less than the value of the commercial paper. 
It  is  crucial  to  recognize  and  appreciate  the  differences  in  opinion  even  though  the
opposite opinion  is  seems  to be weak.  Especially  in  the  situation  in which all parties
involved  are  qualified  and  have  their  own  evidences  and  interpretations  which  are
guided by  true  ijtihad  (intellectual effort) guidelines. We must also  realize  that  there  is
still room for ijtihad, particularly in the Fiqh Muamalat issue which fall under the Islamic
Legal Maxims  “it  is a  fundamental principle  that  rulings  in  Islamic  transaction must be
taken  into  account  it  objectives”.  Therefore,  as  long  as  there  no  ijma’  (consensus  of
jurist) that forbids Bay’ ad-Dayn, it is not healthy to condemn other ijtihad. However the
best  way  suggested  in  this  kind  of  issue  is  “Get  out  from  the  disputation  is  always
recommended”. Thus, it’s better to avoid Bay’ Ad-dayn when there is alternative. 
 let us for the sake of argument support the view that the sale of debt is allowed and a
system  which  involves  selling  of  debt  should  be  maintained  and  expand  our
understanding a  little  further  for  the stretch of  imagination  in  the  light of  few  following
cases because  the moment we support  then due  to  the  inated   virulence   of  it,    this  is
how it unfolds as we will judge it through certain pomp financial instruments which base
on the allowance-the syndrome which is trying to sink its teeth in Islamic finance.
19


6.0                                          WISDOM PERSONAFIED
6.1. IT WAS ALWAYS MEANT TO BE LIKE THIS:
The  sale of debt  to  third parties, especially  through multiple  securitizations, has been
blamed  for  fueling  the  worst  global  financial  crisis  in  generations.  Although  some
banking experts still say the sale of debt is key to developing a liquid secondary Islamic
bond market and a deeper, more sophisticated sharia banking system.
The  global  total  of  asset-backed  securities  issued  and  sold  to  investors  fell  by  79
percent to $441 billion in 2008, as overleveraged borrowers, banks and investors exited
the market, according to think-tank International Financial Services London.
Some debt financing has always been part of  the financial markets. Even  in heyday of
Islamic civilization  trade credit, a form of debt  financing,  thrived.  Islam has no problem
with  that as  it fits  in with prohibition of exchanging money now with a  larger amount of
money after a period of time. The problem starts with sale of debt, whether created by a
money loan or owed as a price of goods sold on credit. Sale of debt is allowed at par or
face value. But  there can hardly be a market  for exchanging debts at par. You have a
market  for debt when bond  [i.e., debt] prices are determined by supply and demand. 
Sale of debt  implies  selling  risk  [or  shifting  risk]. A  thriving market  for debts at prices
determined by supply and demand  [as  in conventional bond markets]  is vulnerable  to
gambling  like  speculation  as  there  exists  no  objective  basis  for  measuring  risks  of
20

default.  The  changing  prices  reflect  changing  subjective  perceptions  of  the  risks
involved. As  is well  known  these perceptions  can  sometimes be manipulated  through
planting stories in the media.
Remarkably, a ban on selling debts would drastically reduce the outstanding volume of
debt.  In  effect  it  would  scale  down  the  volume  of  outstanding  debts  to  the  level  of
existing real assets. The  inverted pyramid of debts, standing on a slender base of real
wealth, would  be  replaced  by  a  rectangular  column  of  debts,  owed  against  an  equal
amount of real goods and services acquired. The volatility in the bond market is directly
related  to  the  total  volume  of  bonds.  The  larger  the  volume  of  debts,  the weaker  its
connection with real wealth, and the more the scope for gambling-like speculation.
6.1.1. CASE OF DERIVATIVES:
Derivatives also  involve excessive uncertainty. They facilitate managing certain market
risks  (related  to prices,  rates of exchange, etc.). Chance  remains  the basic element  in
the situation, however, expectations being based on pure speculation. Derivatives  too
are a zero sum game: you lose what I gain, unlike the win-win situations in trade or risk
sharing.   The  claim  that  they  increase  liquidity  and  improve  operational  market
efficiency  in  financial  markets  remains  unsubstantiated.  What  can  be  empirically
established  is  that,  whatever  the  initial  benefits  for  a  certain  class  of  investors,
availability of derivatives invites speculative activity. 


21

6.1.2. CASE OF FUTURES (which potentially can spill future)
Futures  trading  may  be  said  to  proceed  over  deferred  and  unpaid  debts.  A  debt  is
normally created by a trader who enters the market either as buyer or seller without any
physical  exchange  of  values.  The  debt  so  originated may  subsequently  become  the
subject of an offset or a  reverse  transaction and a chain of sales and purchases may
follow  that amount essentially of  the sale of debts. The offsetting  transaction  in futures
also  consist  of  sales  involving  a  debt  that  one  party  owes  to  another  and  settles  it
through  the modality  of  sale  and  purchase. Many  types  of  sales  have  been  included
under bay al duyuun (lit., sale of debts, also known as bay al kali bi al kali), and it has
been disputed as to whether some of them do in fact qualify as “sale of debts.” It will be
noted  that  the  fiqh  concept  of  bay  al-dayn  referred  to  transactions  over  debts  in  the
open  market  without  any  guarantees.  Bay  al-dayn  basically  envisaged  sale  over  an
unpaid debt involving either two, or in some cases, three parties. The basic rationale of
the prohibition of bay al-dayn was over uncertainty in its repayment. Bay al-dayn could
proceed over a bad debt or one in which the debtor simply wanted a further delay due to
his  inability  to pay on  time. Subsequent unfavorable price changes also added  to  that
uncertainty.  The  situation  is  very  different  in  the  futures  market  now  where  all
transactions  are  concluded  over  guaranteed  debts.  The  critics  have  not  hesitated,
however, to pass judgments and say: since the buyer in futures does not pay the price
to  the seller nor does  the  latter  take delivery,  they  transact over debts and  indulge  in
bay  al-kali  bil-kali,  which  is  prohibited  Some  instances  of  bay  al-dayn  bil-dayn  are
illustrated as follows: 
22

1.A borrows two tons of wheat for his personal needs from B. This amount is returnable
in six months. Prior to the expiration date, B sells the wheat, which is a debt on A, to C
in  exchange  for  a  ploughing machine  to  be  delivered  in  one month.  This  transaction
proceeds over an exchange of debts and is considered unlawful due to uncertainty over
delivery and the resulting likelihood of gharar.
2. A borrows $2,000 from B for a period of one year, but before repayment is made, B
suggests  to A  that he will rent A’s house  in exchange  for  the sum owed  to B. This  too
involves  selling  one  debt  for  another  without  delivery  on  either  side.  If  the  proposed
exchange  is advantageous  to one party,  it will also  involve unlawful gain amounting  to
riba.
3. A owes B RM1,000 payable  in six months. Upon expiry of six months B asks A  to
give him a ton of wheat in exchange to be delivered in one year.
4. A sells a garment to B for RM1,000 payable on spot, and then buys from B the same
or a similar garment for RM1,200 payable in one year. This transaction ([inah), although
validated  by  the  Shafi[is,  is  invalidated  by  other  schools  as  it  involves  riba  and,
according  to  others,  because  it  is  a  sale  of  debts. The  following Hadith  is  quoted  as
evidence on  the subject: Musa  ibn  [Ubayd  reported  from  [Abd Allah  ibn  [Umar simply
that “the Prophet prohibited bay al kali bi al kali.



23

6.1.3. CASE OF SALE AND SECURITIZATION OF DEBT:
The  second  issue we  take  up  is  the  sale  of  debt,  bai  ‘al-dayn. Prohibition  of  interest
almost eliminates the direct lending of money for business. So there is no bond market
in an Islamic economy whose liquidity should become an issue. Direct lending of money
is replaced by murabaha and similar credit transactions, effectively tying the expansion
of  credit  with  the  growth  of  the  economy.  In  place  of  conventional  treasury  bonds
Islamic  financial markets have bonds based on  Ijara  (leasing), Salam  (prepaid orders)
or  Istisna‘  (manufacturing orders on a pay as you get basis). But  there also  is a huge
debt  created  by  installment  sales  and murabaha.  To  some, making  all  these wait  till
maturity implies waste. This waste occurs at two levels. Firstly, those holding IOUs will
need  credit  to  command  real  resources  in  order  to  continue  producing,  having
presumably  exhausted  their  own  resources  in  producing  what  they  already  sold  on
credit.  This  means  the  society  will  always  carry  lots  of  illiquid  assets,  the  IOUs.
Secondly,  this may  force sellers/producers  to refuse selling on credit, demanding cash
instead. A society in which all IOUs must await redemption by the original debtor cannot
economize  on  the  use  of  cash.  This  is  rather  inefficient  (but  not  a  big  deal  in  a  fiat
currency regime!). 
It may rightly be pointed out that somebody must await maturity of debts incurred in the
process  of  acquiring  command  over  real  resources  on  credit. As Keynes  pointed  out
commenting  on  the  ‘liquidity  fetish’,  not  everybody  can  be  liquid  all  the  time.  It  is,
however, more efficient  to provide opportunities  for exchange between  those who are
willing  to wait and share  the  risks  involved  (as  the  Islamic  framework does not  reward
24

pure  waiting)  and  those  who  seek  liquidity.  One  way  to  do  so  is  to  allow  IOUs  as
collaterals for fresh credit---a practice already in vogue in the Islamic financial market. It
is  also  permissible  to  exchange  these  IOUs  for  goods  and  services.  But  some  want
more, let us see if they can have it.
The  juristic objection  to sale of debts  resulting  from murabaha, etc.  is  the same as  in
case of selling a debt created by a money loan. If I buy for 90 an IOU worth 100 after a
year,  I am doing so  in order  to earn 10 as  interest. They see no  reason  to distinguish
between  IOUs created by murabaha and  IOUs created by  lending money. This seems
to be underlying the latest Islamic Fiqh Academy resolution on the subject that states: ‘It
is not permissible  to sell a deferred debt by  the non-debtor  for a prompt cash, from  its
type or otherwise, because this results in Riba (usury). Likewise it is not permissible to
sell  it  for a deferred cash,  from  its  type or otherwise, because  it  is similar  to a sale of
debt for debt which is prohibited in Islam. There is no difference whether the debt is the
result  of  a  loan  or  whether  it  is  deferred  sale’  (Islamic  Fiqh  Academy,  2000,  p.234).
However, the view equating, in this context, money loans and debts resulting from credit
has  been  challenged. There  are  reasons  to  treat  the  two  differently,  say Chapra  and
Khan  :  ‘The  debt  is  created  by    the  murabaha  mode  of  financing  permitted  by  the
Shariah and  the price, according  to  the  fuqaha  themselves,  includes  the profit on  the
transaction and not interest. Therefore, when the bank sells such a debt instrument at a
discount, what it is relinquishing, or what the buyer is getting, is not interest but rather a
share  in  profit’  (Chapra  and Khan,  2000,  p.78).  In  other words,  a  debt  resulting  from
murabaha has an element absent from a debt arising from borrowing money-- the mark
25

up on spot price. Sale and purchase of murabaha-based debt would take place on this
extra profit margin.
The problem with this proposition is that what was a profit margin for the seller of goods
and  services  (on  a murabaha  basis) may  not  necessarily  remain  so when  the  same
seller  ‘sells’  the  IOU arising  from  that  transaction. Some of  the  factors  involved  in  the
determination  of  the mark  up  on  spot  price  in murabaha may  be  different  from  those
involved  in  the  sale  of  the  resulting  IOU  at  a  discount.  Furthermore,  the  extra  profits
earned  in murabaha sale, over and above  those earnable on selling  for cash, are still
against  sale  of  goods  and  services.  But  the  part  of  it  that  goes  to  the  buyer  of  the
murabaha based IOU (according to the above mentioned rationalization) has no goods
and services corresponding to it. It is money for money, with a difference of dates.
The authors go on to argue that there is hardly any gharar involved in the sale of debtinstruments
 under discussion, a point we may ignore because of the limited purpose of
this paper. What interests me is their plea that the fuqaha reconsider the case of assetbased
  debt  instruments  and  allow  their  sale  as  it  would  lead  ‘to  the  accelerated
development of an Islamic money market’ (ibid, p. 79) They proceed to emphasize the
need for such a market by pointing out that Islamic banks may face a liquidity crunch in
its absence, paralyzing  the whole system. They also believe  ‘it  is difficult  for banks  to
play effectively their role of financial intermediation, without being able to securitize their
receivables’  (Chapra  and  Khan,  2000,  p.79).  After  discussing  alternative  avenues  of
raising  large  funds  required by  client  companies  through banks,  they  conclude  that  ‘it
26

would  be  preferable  to  allow  banks  to  rely  on  the  sale  of  their  own  assets  to  raise
liquidity.’( ibid, p.80 ) 
So it is efficiency that is at stake, in an environment where the inefficient may not long
survive. Once  again  the  same  story:  the  jurists  bent  on  ensuring  justice  by  avoiding
anything similar  to  riba/interest and  the economists keen  to maintain efficient markets.
Do they understand each other’s concerns? Is the rationale (hikmah) of prohibiting riba
also applicable  to sale of debts  resulting  from murabaha so  that  it must be blocked  to
ensure  justice? What about a  trade-off between  the  two objectives of Shariah,  justice
and wealth creation? Is such a trade off acceptable under certain circumstances? Does
it  become  unavoidable  sometimes?  Can  we  agree  on  some  formula  that  ensures  a
reasonable  degree  of  fairness with  a  reasonable  level  of efficiency? These  questions
have yet to be thoroughly examined. Those arguing in favor of legitimizing sale of debt
have  to  demonstrate  that  no  alternative  methods  of  ensuring  liquidity  are  available.
They have also to meet the objection that once sale of debt is allowed insofar as asset
based IOUs are concerned, prohibiting the sale of IOUs based on money lending will be
difficult, if not impossible, to sustain.
 Bai‘ al-dayn is approved by Malaysian Shariah scholars (Securities Commission, 2002).
It has a place in Islamic banking as practiced in Southeast Asia. Shariah scholars in that
region  which  follows  the  Shafi  ‘i  school  of  Islamic  Law  base  their  opinion  on  certain
rulings which  the  scholars  in  the heartland of  Islamic  finance  following  other  schools,
generally  speaking,  do  not  agree  with  (Usmani,  2000).  Bank  Islam  Malaysia  is
marketing Negotiable  Islamic Deposit Certificates  (NIDC) backed by murabaha based
27

assets (Archer and Karim, 2002, p.132). ‘In Malaysia the Islamic benchmark bond was
introduced  in 1990 and  is believed  to be based on  the murabahah concept. They are
the most popular  form of  Islamic  financing method used  in Malaysia’  (al-Amine, 2001,
p.3). Al-Amine goes on  to note, however,  the controversy  that still surrounds  the Shari
‘ah legitimacy of these bonds (ibid, p.4). 
Many  Islamic  debt  instruments  on  sale  in  the Malaysian market  are  criticized  on  the
ground  that  they  involve bay‘ al-dayn and bay‘al-‘inah  (Rosley and Sanusi, 1999). But
some  scholars  refer  to  certain  Hanbali  and  Maliki  jurists  (.e.g.,  Ibn  e  Qayyim  and
Dasuqi,  respectively  ) who  ‘are  of  the  opinion  that  selling  dayn  to  a  third  party  is  not
against syarak  (shar‘)’    [Ishak.1997, p.6].It  is noted  that  there  is a difference between
the  debtor  being  asked  by  the  creditor  to  pay more  than  the  price  agreed  upon  in  a
credit sale in lieu of delay in payment, and selling the IOU arising from that credit sale to
a  third  party.  In  the  latter  case  the  seller  on  credit, who  holds  the  IOU,  is  no  longer
dealing with the debtor. He is dealing with a third party to whom he sells the IOU. The
deal between  this  third party, which now holds  the  IOU, and  the debtor,  is  free of  the
constraints attending upon the deal between the seller on credit and the one who buys
on credit.  ‘Bay al-dayn to a third party, however, is different because a third party does
not ask  for  increase  in price  from  the debtor. The debtor will  just pay according  to  the
initial contract. As dayn has been sold  to a  third party,  the  initial creditor will no  longer
make a claim but the third party will.’(Ishak, 1997, p.7). Ishak proceeds to argue, ‘ Can
haq al-dayn (be) sold at a lower price? The answer is yes, because it is not a currency
and the attributes transferred when bought consist of haq mall not currency…….Based
on the above, if the  initial seller is willing to reduce his right and give the third party the
28

full  right,  it  is  not  at  all  against  syriah  (Shari  ‘ah)  principles.  The  same  with  share
certificates traded, it is an ownership right in a company and when sold in the secondary
market the price is essentially different from the initial price’ (Ishak, 1997, p.7).
Does not sound very convincing, as a shareholder does not hold a claim  to a definite
sum  of money  to  be  paid  in  future.  But  there  is  no  need  for  me  to  evaluate  these
arguments in analogical terms. What I am interested in is their focus on distancing sale
of  debt  from  riba/interest  and  trying  to  show  it  is  fair  trade,  free  of  injustice  as
symbolized by riba/interest. Hence  the claim  that asset based securities are  like share
certificates  and  necessary  for  the well  being  of  people.  This  is  evidenced  by  Ishak’s
appeal to the ‘syari‘ah (Shari ‘ah) principles of ra’fah and  takhfif’ in his conclusion ( ibid,
p.8  ).In other words,  it  is being asserted  that allowing  sale of debt arising  from  credit
sales  is  neither  unjust  nor  unfair  as  it  does  not  involve  riba/interest.  Also  it  is
emphasized that it should be allowed in order to make life easy and prosperous. I think
it  would  have  been  better  if  instead  of  finding  an  analogy  between  a  certificate  of
ownership in a company and an IOU, Ishak had pursued the maslaha based arguments
on which he concludes.
It would  be  far  better  to  conduct  the  debate  openly  in  the  framework  of  ease  versus
hardship,  efficiency  versus  fairness,  growth  versus  distribution.  The  trade-offs  could
then be openly examined, sometime even measured. At  the macroeconomic  level, we
need to know why liquidity cannot be guaranteed without legitimizing the sale of debt. It
has  to  be  discussed  how  giving  debt-financing  a  greater  role  is  likely  to  change  the
nature  of  Islamic  economy  which  emphasizes  risk  sharing  and  participatory  finance.
29

Alas! That is not the way legal issues are handled, especially in an industry in a hurry,
as the Islamic financial industry currently seems to be, under tremendous pressure from
its more  ‘efficient’  competitors. While  the Shariah  scholar  sitting on an  Islamic  bank’s
advisory  board may  have  barely  the  time  to  check  the  relevant  texts  and  whether  a
particular  analogical  reasoning  is  acceptable,  the  task  of  the  social  scientists/moral
philosophers  is  more  contemplative,  time  taking.  An  appeal  to  maqasid  al-shariah
(objectives of Shari ‘ah) is not that easy as it may seem to the un-initiated. It involves a
far deeper understanding of  Islam as a way of  life, a process of social  reconstruction
and  a mission with  humanity  that  one would  normally  expect  in  a  legal  expert  these
days.  Islamic Finance  is about all  these objectives, some of which are hard  to  realize
through analogical reasoning, even financial engineering.
7.0. CONCLUSION:
The above literature is a self explanatory pragma which analyzes the whole dimension
of trade in Islam which submerges in it the qualification of mal and hence its origination
of becoming a permissible subject matter derived from which understanding, extricates
the  very  realm of  the non-permissibility of  the  controversial and enigmatic  sarrogative
subject  matter,  trade  of  which  violates  the  very  basics  norms  of  shariah  hence
sabotaging    harnessing  of  the  society  .this  article  has  tried  to  showcase  the  Islamic
wisdom of why permissible qualification of a subject matter is pivotal and why the debt
as permissible subject matter is debarred ruling out the sale of it.
It proves that allowance of debt salability creates a black hole environment which sucks
the blood out of  real sector  into  virtualism by providing breeding ground  to excessive
30

risk  taking, speculation showcased by cases on derivatives and  futures, securitization
hence sale of debt, catapult of which is deterioration in from of the present crisis.
Islamic  allowance  of  permissible  property  for  trade  and  debt  as  the  opposite
substantiate  the very  fact  that how  Islam  is always  trying  to provide  justice and avoid
disputes as to harness not only the individual but the society as a whole. An approach
of do good and have good under the ambit of a just society.






31

                                                                APPENDIX
                                   OPINION OF THE PAST ISLAMIC JURISTS:
Hanafi Mazhab
The Hanafis are unanimous in not permitting bay al-dayn with reason that the debt is in the form
of mal hukmi (intangible property) and the buyer takes great risk because he cannot own the item
bought and the seller can not deliver the item sold.
Maliki Mazhab
The Malikis allow bay al-dayn subject to certain conditions as follows:
•  Expediting the payment.
•  Debtor present at the place of sale.
•  Debtor confirms the debt.
•  Debtor belongs to the group that is bound by law so that he is able to redeem his debt.
•  Payment  is not  the  same  type as dayn, and  it  fit  so, and  the  rate  should be  the  same  to
avoid riba.
•  The debt cannot be created from the sale of currency (gold and silver) to be delivered in
future date.
•  The  dayn  should  be  goods  that  are  saleable  even  before  they  are  received.  This  is  to
ensure that the dayn is not of the food type which cannot be traded before qabadh occur.
32

•  There should be no enmity between the buyer and seller, which can create difficulties to
the debtor.
Shafi’i Mazhab
The Shafi’i allows the selling of debt to a third party if the dayn was mustaqir (guaranteed) and
was sold in exchange for goods that must be delivered immediately. The debt is sold; it must be
paid in cash or tangible assets as agreed.
The  Securities Commission  Shariah Advisory Council  held  that  in  the  context  of  the  sales  of
securitized debt,  the  characteristic of  securities differentiates  it  from  currency.  It  is not  a  legal
tender and therefore, it is not bound by the conditions for exchanging of goods. It is not a ribawi
item as the fifth condition set by Maliki mazhab.









33

BIBLIOGRAPHY:


•  S.E. Rayner, The Theory of Contracts of Islamic Law, Graham & Trotman,
London, 1991 
•  Mawlana Taqi Usmani, An Introduction to Islamic Finance, Idaratul Maarif,
Karachi, 1998 
•  Uduvitch, Partnership and Profit in Medieval Islam, Princeton University Press,
1970 
•  M. Tahir Mansuri, Islamic Law of Contract and Business Transactions, Adam
Publishers & Distributors, New Delhi, 2006 
•  Razali Nawawi, Islamic Law on Commercial Transactions, CT Publications
Malaysia, 2000. 
•  Alaeddin Kharufah, Transaction in Islamic Law, A.S. Nordeen, Kuala Lumpur
20048. Liaqat Ali Khan Niazi, Islamic Law of Contract.
•  The Majelle, (the Ottoman Civil Law based on Hanafi school) Published by Open
Press KL 
•  The Hidayah, English translation by Hamilton of the Arabic Hanafi Fiqh Manual:
al-Hidayah .
•  Nabil Salih, Unlawful Gain and Legitimate Profit in Islamic Law, Graham &
Trotman, 1992 Abdul Barr, Muhammad Zaki (1990 ), Raiun Aakhar fi Matl al-
Madin, hal yulzam bi’l-Ta‘wid?, Journal of King Abdulaziz University:Islamic
Economics (Jeddah ),vol.2, pp.155-160.
34


•  Abdul Barr, Muhammad Zaki (1991) Ta‘liq, Journal of King Abdulaziz University
:Islamic Economics (Jeddah), vol.3, pp.61-62 (Arabic/English Section)

•  Al-Amine, Muhammad al-Bashir Muhammad (2001) The Islamic Bond Market:
Possibilities and Challenges, International Journal of Islamic Financial Services,
vol.3, no. 1, April-June , <http://Islamic-finance.net/journal.html>

•  ‘Attiyah, Jamal (1990 ) al-Jawanib al-Qanuniyah li Tatbiq ‘aqd al-Murabaha,
Journal of King Abdulaziz University: Islamic Economics (Jeddah ),vol.2, pp.125-
145.

•  Chapra, M.U and Tariqullah Khan (2000), Regulation and Supervision of Islamic
Banks, Jeddah, Islamic Research and Training Institute, Islamic Development
Bank

•  Al-Dareer, al-Siddiq Muhammad al-Amin (1985) al-Ittifaq ‘ala Ilzam al-Madin al-
Mu’sir bi Ta ‘wid Darar al-Mumatalah, Journal of Research in Islamic Economics
(Jeddah), vol.3, no.1, pp.111-112.

•  al-Dareer, al-Siddiq Muhammad al- Amin (1993) Ta‘liq, Journal of King Abdulaziz
University : Islamic Economics (Jeddah),vol.5, pp.69-77.

35

•  Al-Dareer, Muhammad Siddiq al-Amin ( 1993 ) Ta ‘liq, Journal of King Abdulaziz
University : Islamic Economics (Jeddah),vol5,pp.63-67.

•  Elgari,Mohammad Ali,Mohammad Nejatullah Siddiqi and Mohammad Anas
Zarqa (1993) Qanun al-Masarif-- Sighah Muqterahah li-Tanzeem Qita ‘in Masrafi
Islami, Review of Islamic Economics (Leicester),vol. 2, no. 2,1993, pp.67-97.

•  Hammad, Nazeeh Kamal ( 1985 ) al-Muwayi’dat al-Shar‘iyah li Haml al-Madin al-
Mumatil ‘ala’l-Wafa’   wa Butlan al-Hukm bi’l Ta‘wid al-Mali  ‘an Darar al-
Mumatalah, Journal of Research in Islamic Economics (Jeddah ),vol.3,no.1,pp.
101-108.

•  Ishak, Dato  Othman Hj. (1997 ), Developing Dha‘ wa Ta ‘ajjal in Structuring
Islamic Instruments, Paper presented at the International Capital Market
Conference held at Kuala Lumpur on 15-16 July ,1997  

•  Islamic Fiqh Academy (2000) Resolutions and Recommendations of the Council
of the Islamic Fiqh Academy 1985-2000, Jeddah, Islamic Research and Training
Institute, Islamic Development Bank 

•  Al-Kaff, Habib Hamid Abdul Rahman (1993), Ta ‘liq, Journal of King Abdulaziz
University: Islamic Economics (Jeddah), vol3, pp.63-64.

36

•  Al-Roobi, Rabi‘( 1992), Ta ‘liq, Journal of King Abdulaziz University : Islamic
Economics   (Jeddah),vol4,pp.67-69.

•  Saleh, Ibn al-Haj Mohammad (2002) al-Ta ‘wid ‘ind al-Takhir fi al-Sidad bain al-
Mu ‘aradah wa’l Ta’id in Majallat al-Masarif, (Khartoum) No.1 June

•  Securities Commission (2002) Resolutions of the Securities Commission
Syariyah Advisory Council, Kuala Lumpur, March
•  Usmani, Muhammad Taqi (2000) Bay ‘ al-Dayn wa’l Awraq al-Maliyah wa
Badailuha al-Shar‘iyah, in Dirasat Iqtisadiyah Islamiyah ( Jeddah), vol. 7, no.
1,pp.7-34  

•  State Bank of Pakistan (2004) Press Release: State Bank’s       Shari ‘ah Board
Approves Essentials and Model Agreements for Islamic Modes of Financing,
April 16 (http://www.sbp.org.pk/press/2004/Islamic_modes.pdf)

•  Al-Zarqa, Mohammad Anas and Mohammad Ali Elgari (1991),  al-Ta ‘wid ‘an
Darar al-Mumatalah fi’l Dayn Bain al-Fiqh wa’l Iqtisad, Journal of King Abdulaziz
University :Islamic Economics (Jeddah ),vol.3, pp.25-25-56 

•  Al-Zarqa, Mustafa Ahmed (1985 ) Hal Yuqbal Shar‘an al-Hukm  ‘ala’l-Madin al-
Mumatil bi’l Ta ‘wid ‘ala al-Da’ in?, Journal of Research in Islamic Economics
(Jeddah), vol.2, no.2, pp 89-97.